MA ECONOMICS

MA ECONOMICS


NOTES AVAILABLE IN REASONABLE PRICE

NOTES AVAILABLE IN REASONABLE PRICE

Macroeconomics and Microeconomics: Chit Chat

  CHIT-CHAT TIME           Commerce Heaven (In this conversation after getting 1000 Rupees Khalid is going with his friend Tariq to purcha...

Thursday, April 20, 2017

9 Most Important Properties of Indifference Curves



(1) A higher indifference curves to the right of another represents a higher level of satisfaction and preferable combination of the two goods. In Figure 6, consider the indifference curves I1 and I2 and combination N and A respectively on them.
Since A is on a higher indifference curve and to the right of N, the consumer will be having more of both the goods X and Y that is, OX1 + OY1 in relation to OX + OY. Even if the two points on these curves are on the same plane as M and A, the consumer will prefer the latter combination, because he will be having more of good X though the quantity of good Y is the same.
The indifference curves I1 and I2 and combination N and A respectively on them
(2) In between two indifference curves there can be a number of other indifference curves, one for every point in the space on the diagram.
(3) The numbers I1, I2, I3, I4,………… etc. given to indifference curves are absolutely arbitrary. Any numbers can be given to indifference curves. The numbers can be in the ascending order of 1, 2, 4, 6 or 2, 3, 1, 4 etc. Numbers have no importance in the indifference curve analysis.
(4) The slope of an indifference curve is negative, downward sloping, and from left to right. It means that the consumer to be indifferent to all the combinations on the indifference curves must leave less units of good Y in order to have more of good X. To prove this property, let us take indifference curves contrary to this assumption. In Figure 7 (A) combination B of OX1 + OY1 is preferable to combination A which has a smaller amount of the two goods. Therefore, the indifference curve cannot slope upward from left to right. It is not an iso-utility curve.
Similarly, in Figure 7 (B) combination B is preferable to combination A for combination B has more of X and the same quantity of Y. So the indifference curve cannot be horizontal. In Figure 7 (C) the indifference curve is shown as vertical and again combination B is preferred to A as the consumer has more of Y and the same quantity of X. Therefore, the indifference curve cannot be vertical either. Consequently, the indifference curve will be of negative slope as shown in Figure 7 (D) where A and B combinations give equal satisfaction to the consumer. As he moves from combination A to B he gives up less quantity of Y in order to have more of X.
The indifference curve will be of negative slope

(5) Indifference curves can neither touch nor intersect each other so that one indifference curve passes through only one point on an indifference map. What absurdity follows from such a situation can be shown with the help of Figure 8 (A) where the two curves I1and I2 cut each other. Point A on the I1 curve indicates a higher level of satisfaction than point B on the I2 curve, as it lies farther away from the origin. But point C which lies on both the curves yields the same level of satisfaction as points A and B. Thus
This is absurd because A is preferred to B, begin on a higher indifference curve I1. Since each indifference curve represents a different level of satisfaction, indifference curves can never inter­sect at any point. The same reasoning applies if two indifference curves touch each other at point С in Panel (B) of the figure.
(6) An indifference curve cannot touch either axis. If it touches X-axis as 7, in Figure 9 at M, the consumer will be having OM quantity of good X and none of Y. Similarly, if an in difference curve I2touches the У-axis at L the consumer will have only OL of Y good and no amount of X. Such curves are in contradiction to the as­sumption that the consumer buys two goods in combinations.
The consumer will be having OM quantity of good X and none of Y

(7) An important property of indifference curves is that they are convex to the origin. The convexity rule implies that as the consumer substitutes X for Y the marginal rate of substitution diminishes. It means that as the amount X is increased by equal amounts that of Y diminish by smaller amounts. The slope of the curve becomes smaller as we move to the right. To prove this, let us take a concave curve where the marginal rate of substitution of X for Y increases instead of diminishing, i.e., more of Y is given up to have additional units of X. As in Figure 10 (A) the consumer is giving up ab< cd< ef units of Y for be = de =fg units of X. But the indifference curve cannot be concave to the origin.
If we take a straight line indifference curve at an angle of 45° with either axis, the marginal rate of substitution between the two goods will be constant, as in Panel (B) where ab of Y = be of X and cd of Y = de of X. Thus an indifference curve cannot be a straight line.
Figure 10 (C) shows the indifference curve as convex to the origin.
The indifference curve as convex to the origin
Here the consumer is giving up less and less units of Y in order to have equal additional units of X, i.e., ab> cd> ef of Y for be = de — fg of X. Thus an indifference curve is always convex to the origin because the marginal rate of substitution between the two goods declines.
(8) Indifference curves are not necessarily parallel to each other. Though they are falling, negatively inclined to the right, yet the rate of fall will not be the same for all indifference curves. In other words, the dimin­ishing marginal rate of substitution between the two goods is essentially not the same in the case of all indifference schedules. The two curves I1and I2 shown in figure 11 are not parallel to each other.
Indifference curves
(9) In reality indifference curves are like bangles. But as a matter of principle their ‘effective region’ in the form of segments is shown in Figure 12. This is so because indifference curves are assumed to be negatively sloping and convex to the origin. An individual can move to higher indifference curves I1and I2 until he reaches the saturation point 5 where his total utility is the maxi­mum.
indifference curves

If the consumer increases his consumption more than OX or OY, his total utility will fall. If he increases his consumption of X so as to reach the dotted portion of the I1 curve horizontally from point S to N he gets negative utility. If to compensate himself for this loss of utility, he increases the consumption of Y, he may be again on the dotted portion of the curve, vertically from point S to M. Thus the consumer may be on the concave portion of the circular curve. Since by moving to the dotted portion he gets negative utility, the effective region of the circular curve will be the convex portion.

No comments:

Post a Comment

GEO COUNTER

Total Pageviews

Subscribe to cost-accountants

Powered by us.groups.yahoo.com

CLASSES

CLASSES

Guess Papers

Guess Papers